Page 201 - DECO503_INTERNATIONAL_TRADE_AND_FINANCE_ENGLISH
P. 201

Unit 17 : Process of Adjustments : Gold Standard, Fixed Exchange Rates and Flexible Exchange Rate



        Such a system has two major advantages. The first is that fixed exchange rates imply reduced  Notes
        uncertainty, and this helps reduce the costs of international trade transactions. The second is that
        fixed exchange rates act as to discipline monetary authorities, preventing them from pursuing
        inflationary policies. This argument was emphasized when Brazil and Argentina adopted fixed-
        exchange-rate-based arrangements in the 1990s. The logic is that excessive money supply expansion
        generates inflation that, in turn, gives agents an incentive to shift into currencies with purchasing
        power that is not being eroded. Such shifts force the central bank to intervene and buy the currency
        to protect the exchange rate, thereby reducing the money supply. In this fashion, fixed exchange
        rates establish an automatic mechanism that prevents central banks from excessive money supply
        expansion, and central banks are forced to tighten the money supply whenever inflation starts to
        increase to levels that will spur currency flight. This mechanism is referred to as a nominal anchor,
        with the exchange rate serving to anchor the price level. In countries with histories of excessive
        inflation and where central banks have lost credibility with financial markets, it is argued that
        employing a fixed-exchange-rate nominal anchor is a good way to win back credibility. Moreover,
        the costs of such commitment are small if monetary policy is viewed as being unable to systematically
        impact equilibrium real interest rates and the equilibrium level of real economic activity.
        Balanced against these advantages are several disadvantages. First, by committing to a fixed exchange
        rate, a country gives up having the exchange rate as a shock absorber that helps insulate against
        external economic shocks. Second, the fixed exchange rate limits the ability to use domestic monetary
        policy to stabilize the economy, but, as noted above, this loss can be beneficial in cases where monetary
        authorities have a credibility problem due to past high inflation.
        Third, the nature of the adjustment process under fixed exchange rates may have a significant
        deflationary bias. Abstracting from capital flows, countries with trade surpluses will experience an
        excess demand for their currencies, while countries with trade deficits will experience an excess
        supply of their currencies. If a deficit country is forced to keep buying its currency to defend the
        exchange rate, this leads to domestic monetary contraction in the deficit country, while the money
        supply of the surplus country increases due to the selling of foreign reserves by the deficit country.
        The classical macroeconomic assumption is that reductions in the money supply cause prices to decline
        but have no impact on output. This is the “neutrality of money proposition,” whereby output and
        employment are determined by real economic factors (tastes, resources, and productive technology)
        and not by the amount of circulating paper (i.e., money). Applied to the global economy with fixed
        exchange rates, these money supply changes cause prices to fall in the deficit country and rise in the
        surplus country, thereby altering relative competitiveness and eliminating the trade deficit. However,
        such global monetarist reasoning is contested by Keynesian analysis that argues that monetary
        contraction induces real output contraction that is worsened by price deflation due to debt effects.
        The net result is that the adjustment process under fixed exchange rates causes domestic output
        contraction that ricochets back into the international economy, as falling domestic income causes
        reduced imports, in turn, reducing aggregate demand and income in other countries.
        One possible way to avoid this contractionary outcome is to require the surplus country to defend its
        currency and prevent it from appreciating, rather than require the deficit country to do the defending.
        In this case, the system is prone to an expansionary bias, because the surplus country increases its
        money supply to prevent appreciation. However, this arrangement removes the discipline of fixed
        exchange rates on central banks. A second option for reducing contractionary bias is to have periodic
        discrete adjustments of the fixed exchange rate to eliminate fundamental trade imbalances. This was
        the Bretton Woods approach. However, it also removes (or at least significantly weakens) the discipline
        of fixed exchange rates on central banks. Additionally, it does away with the certainty of fixed exchange
        rates and invites market speculation aimed at anticipating or forcing a devaluation.
        One claimed advantage of fixed exchange rates is that they reduce price uncertainty, which is good
        for international trade. However, introducing international capital mobility into a system of fixed
        exchange rates dramatically changes this conclusion. As noted earlier, capital mobility introduces
        portfolio and wealth allocation concerns that impact currency markets. Most importantly, capital
        mobility introduces financial market behaviors of speculation and herding into currency markets.
        These behaviors can render a fixed exchange-rate system financially fragile. If a country has a persistent



                                         LOVELY PROFESSIONAL UNIVERSITY                                       195
   196   197   198   199   200   201   202   203   204   205   206