Page 239 - DECO503_INTERNATIONAL_TRADE_AND_FINANCE_ENGLISH
P. 239

Unit 21 : Static and Dynamic Effects of a Custom Union and Free Trade Organization



        circumstances the benefits of joining the CU would depend to a considerable extent on the height and  Notes
        structure of each of the countries external tariff compared to that of the Customs Union external
        tariff. While in practice a Customs Union external tariff may not be in place at present, for purposes
        of analysis, the Russian tariff is a good proxy of the Customs Union external tariff that had been
        negotiated and will be used for the discussion in this unit. If a country such as Armenia or the Kyrgyz
        Republic with lower external tariffs were to substitute the Russian tariff for its own tariff structure, it
        would increase its unweighted average tariff to 13-14 percent (see table 2). More importantly, assuming
        that following accession of new members, the common external tariff is not changed, the Russian
        tariff exhibits considerably more dispersion compared with the tariff for some of the countries (typically
        between 0 and 30 percent),3 meaning that for selected highly protected products in Russia, the tariff
        would increase significantly. For other countries, adopting the common external tariff would mean
        actually reducing their average tariff.
        Starting with Jacob Viner (1950), international trade economists typically analyze preferential trade
        arrangements, whether members of a FTA or a CU, in terms of trade creation and trade diversion.
        Trade creation in a product occurs, when additional imports come from partner countries which
        displace sales of inefficient domestic producers and these imports are at least as cheap as imports
        from non-partner countries. Trade creation results in  improved welfare for the importing country
        for much the same reasons as increased trade improves a country's welfare. On the other hand, trade
        diversion occurs when suppliers in the rest of the world (who continue to face tariffs) are more
        efficient than partner suppliers, but additional partner country imports displace the more efficient
        suppliers. Trade diversion is typically (but not necessarily) welfare reducing since the home country
        must pay more to import the product from the less efficient partner country suppliers.
        Although the general theory of regional trading arrangements is quite ambiguous in its conclusions,
        we believe some definitive conclusions are possible with respect to the specific customs union under
        consideration, at least for some of the CIS countries. Since the partner countries in the potential
        customs union already have tariff free access to the other CIS markets under the Free Trade Agreement,
        prices in these countries' markets cannot fall as a result of the customs union, i.e., there will be little
        welfare gain from trade creation. Whatever trade creation would occur, would come from third country
        suppliers in those products where the current external tariff in the country is higher than that of the
        Customs Union external tariff. Since welfare costs from a tariff increase with the square of the tariff
        rate, net welfare effects are little impacted by reductions in tariffs by a few percentage points say,
        from ten to seven percent. Rather what is crucial to the welfare effects are the changes that involve
        significant tariff increases.

        Countries with Lower Tariffs Than in the Customs Union
        Prospective partner country suppliers will have the potential, under the higher tariffs of the customs
        union, to raise prices to consumers in other CIS countries by the amount of the tariff preference over
        rest of world imports. In the model we present in the appendix, we assume that they will do so. A
        principal reason we believe they will do so is our judgment that advocates of the customs union
        propose it as a means of expanding protection for inefficient domestic industries throughout the CIS.
        That is, the customs union is an import substitution strategy for inefficient industries, where the
        structure of the tariff is high in those industries that exist in the customs union, especially in Russia.
        In the appendix, we elaborate some additional reasons why we believe they will do so. Thus, a key
        assumption of our model is that prospective members of the customs union face upward sloping
        supply curves from partner country suppliers who will raise prices by the extent of the tariff.
        Moreover, since these countries have tariff free access to markets of the members of the customs
        union and to Russia in particular, the exporters from a CIS country joining the CU will not obtain
        improved access to the Russian market, which is by far the dominant market in the customs union.
        Thus, for countries like the Kyrgyz Republic and Armenia with already liberal external tariffs or
        others like Georgia and Moldova which are also pursuing generally liberal trade policies and assuming
        the common external tariff is not changed following their accession, the usual tradeoffs that must be
        considered in the evaluation of a preferential trade arrangement (trade diversion versus improved
        access and trade creation) do not apply. Thus, the CU would virtually result in pure trade diversion.



                                         LOVELY PROFESSIONAL UNIVERSITY                                       233
   234   235   236   237   238   239   240   241   242   243   244