Page 319 - DECO503_INTERNATIONAL_TRADE_AND_FINANCE_ENGLISH
P. 319

Unit 28 : International Debt Crisis



        the issues. To most analysts, however, it is clear that lenders as well as borrowers are to blame for the  Notes
        abuses and excesses that occurred.
        The OECD put it this way in its 1982 Survey : “It appears in retrospect that certain developing countries
        have borrowed unwisely (as indeed have some other borrowers), using some of the resources to
        finance consumption and investments of dubious value, rather than to strengthen their productive
        potential.” They were able to do so because creditors, primarily banks, did not constrain their lending
        by adhering to normal prudent standards. Rather, “overeagerness by banks to lend has sometimes
        allowed borrowing governments to delay necessary adjustments.”
        Some would absolve banks from blame. They argue that banks would have been less eager to lend to
        developing countries if they had reliable, current information about the total indebtedness of the
        countries to whom they were lending. Through 1982, each bank had timely information only on its
        own loans. However, the argument is not persuasive. One large regional bank, the National Bank of
        Detroit, as reported by Sanford Rose of the American Banker, stopped lending to Mexico by the end of
        1981 based on an in-house analysis of the risk involved. Furthermore, all banks should have understood
        the risk of operating without full information and tempered their eagerness to lend to developing
        countries accordingly. As it was, some banks made loans in excess of their capital to countries that
        are now having trouble meeting their debt-service obligations.
        Regardless of how much blame should be assigned to borrowers and how much to lenders, by the
        summer of 1982 it was clear that some LDCs and Eastern bloc nations were having trouble servicing
        their debts, that their bankers were becoming concerned and reluctant to extend new credits and in
        some cases to renew maturing credits, and that some banks, including some in the United States, had
        made loans to these countries in excess of their capital, some-times in disregard of the advice of in-
        house specialists on sovereign risk. These elements define the current crisis.
        Those who look for proximate causes will tie the emergence of the present debt crisis to the 1981 to
        1982 disinflation and recession. During recessions, especially when accompanied by substantial
        disinflation (to build a springboard for sustainable growth), as in 1982, debts are not easily serviced
        by debtors, nor are they automatically renewed by lenders. This view of the emergence of the debt
        problem has been popularized by the press. The New York Times, for example, wrote on 9 January
        1983, that “what has really gone wrong in the third world can be traced to the weak world economy
        rather than to an overextension of credit by greedy commercial bankers or extravagant borrowing by
        imprudent leaders of developing nations.” The Washington Post wrote on the same day, “The recession
        has sent to the brink of bankruptcy countries once thought to be impeccable credit risks . . . [depressing]
        demand prices for commodities that are the mainstay of the developing world.”
        However, disinflation and recession in the 1981 to 1982 period did not occur in an historical vacuum
        but followed a wave of inflation that began in 1977. The debt crisis can be tied to that inflationary
        surge. Advocates of this view need not dispute that the debt build-up financed “a large amount of
        inflation,” as Kaufman pointed out, or that initially the inflation was associated with robust growth
        figures. Early on, the chain of causation definitely runs from debt accumulation and money creation
        to inflation and growth. Later on, however, the chain of causation runs the other way—from inflation
        to debt accumulation and recession. Inflation undermines household, business, and government
        balance sheets. It creates an atmosphere in which debtors flourish and become eager to borrow, often
        without regard to risk, while lenders downgrade risks. As a result, careless practices creep into the
        lending process and indebtedness increases dangerously. At the same time, even if it is periodically
        ratcheted upward, inflation inevitably produces recessions. Since, as balance sheets deteriorate,
        production and spending fall, especially capital formation and investment spending.
        The inflationary surge of the late 1970s to 1981 is legitimately viewed as the underlying cause of the
        present debt crisis. The 1981 to 1982 recession period was the trigger event. The recession suppressed
        demands for goods and services generally, and because commodity and raw materials markets are
        relatively competitive, commodity and raw materials prices declined relatively more than the prices
        of intermediate and finished goods. In fact, the latter continued to increase on average.
        On balance, non-OPEC developing countries export commodities and raw materials and import
        intermediate and finished goods. Thus, the 1981 to 1982 recession raised their trade and current



                                         LOVELY PROFESSIONAL UNIVERSITY                                       313
   314   315   316   317   318   319   320   321   322   323   324