Page 299 - DPOL202_COMPARATIVE_POLITICS_AND_GOVERNMENT_ENGLISH
P. 299

Comparative Politics and Government


                    Notes          did not really allow ordinary citizens to choose representatives. In 1979, a new election law introduced
                                   direct election of deputies to county-level congresses, mandated secret ballots rather than public
                                   displays of support, and required the number of candidates to be one and a half times the number of
                                   deputies to be elected. Although local Communist Party organizations continue to play a key leadership
                                   role in election committees, essentially vetting candidates, not all candidates can win under current
                                   rules. Some officially nominated candidates lose elections. Indeed, some candidates officially
                                   designated for government office (which requires initial election to congresses) lose elections. A
                                   growing number of candidates who are not communist party members have competed and won in
                                   elections. A smaller number of government executives nominated by deputies are not official
                                   candidates and win without official endorsement. An electoral victory signifies some degree of popular
                                   support, while losing signifies a problematic relationship with the mass public. At a minimum, the
                                   new rules are a means for the Communist Party organization to gauge popular views about local
                                   officials, diversify the pool from which leaders are recruited, and monitor local leaders. To be sure,
                                   the new rules have not produced radical change. Nor can such an outcome be expected without
                                   further change in rules: no platform of opposition to the Communist Party is permissible, and
                                   competition in elections to people’s congresses is restricted to the township and county levels.
                                   In 1997 and 1998, Jiang Zemin and the NPC proclaimed their support for more popular participation
                                   and more competition in elections to township people’s congresses. The idea was neither new nor
                                   borrowed from the liberal democratic tradition. It emerged from a decade of practical experience
                                   with one of the more controversial political reforms of the post-Mao years: grassroots democratization
                                   in the Chinese countryside, formally approved in November 1987 when the NPC, after over a year of
                                   debate, passed a provisional version of the Organic Law on Village Committees. A final revised
                                   version was passed in November 1998. The law defines village committees as “autonomous mass
                                   organizations of self-government,” popularly elected, in elections featuring choice among candidates,
                                   for three-year terms and accountable to a village council comprised of all adult villagers.
                                   The introduction of popularly elected village committees in 1987 had not been a commitment to
                                   process but a gamble on outcomes by leaders at the political center. It was designed to strengthen
                                   state, capacity to govern in the aftermath of agricultural decollectivization. In the early 1980s, the
                                   people’s communes had been dismantled and replaced with township governments. Land and other
                                   production inputs were divided among peasant households to manage on their own, free markets
                                   were opened, most obligatory sales to the state were abolished, and private entrepreneur-ship was
                                   promoted. The results of these reforms were successful by most economic standards, but disastrous
                                   in their consequences for rural leadership. As villagers gained greater economic initiative and
                                   autonomy, the power of the Chinese party-state to exact compliance was enormously weakened. By
                                   the mid-1980s, village leadership had seriously atrophied. Leaders were enriching themselves at the
                                   expense of the community, and villagers were resisting their efforts to implement unpopular policies.
                                   Violent conflicts between villagers and village leaders had become common. The revitalization of
                                   village committees in 1987 was designed to make the countryside more governable by increasing
                                   accountability. Presumably, villagers would be more responsive to leaders elected from below rather
                                   than those imposed from above as before.
                                   With an average size of about 1,200 people, villages are small communities, where most adults have
                                   lived and worked together for decades—and could, therefore, be expected to know and elect capable
                                   and trustworthy leaders to manage village affairs. Presumably too, newly elected village leaders
                                   could serve as loyal agents of the Chinese party-state, guaranteeing policy implementation, acting as
                                   the “legs” of the township governments above them. Success required village management by leaders
                                   elected in processes featuring broad participation by ordinary villagers, electoral choice, and
                                   transparent procedures.
                                   In 1997 and 1998, when top leaders affirmed the experience of village elections, most villages had
                                   undergone at least three rounds of elections, with enormous local variation in implementation. In
                                   many (perhaps most) villages, the village Communist Party branch controlled candidate nomination,
                                   there was no candidate choice for the key position or village committee director, and voting
                                   irregularities were common. Even in villages that made serious progress—with genuinely competitive
                                   elections, widespread popular participation in candidate nomination, and scrupulous attention to


          294                              LOVELY PROFESSIONAL UNIVERSITY
   294   295   296   297   298   299   300   301   302   303   304