Page 222 - DCOM505_WORKING_CAPITAL_MANAGEMENT
P. 222

Unit 13: Integration of Working Capital and Capital Investment Process




          As finished goods inventories are increased, each successive increment recaptures less lost sales  Notes
          and therefore less lost contribution. At levels A and B, E(R) appears to be quite attractive. Policy
          D, returning  only 4.8 per cent  after  taxes, does not  seem attractive.  Which policy  should
          Southeastern adopt? The answer depends on the target or required rate of return on investment
          in inventories.
          An important feature of the analysis above is that it examines the incremental return on successive
          increments of inventory. To move from the current policy to level D would require a total
          investment of ` 6,68,000. This investment would generate additional operating profit of  ` 9600,
          an E(R) of 14.4 per cent. However, the E(R) on the last increment, from level C to level D, is only
          4.8  per cent. By looking at several increments, we  can better determine the point at  which
          marginal E(R) falls below the required rate within increments; the figures in table represent
          averages. The marginal E(R) on the last rupee of investment in increment B is quite a bit lower
          than the average E(R), 22.8 per cent, on increment B as a whole.

          At the aggregate level of the manufacturing sector both in 1975 and in 1982 working capital
          declined sharply; some components, such as accounts receivables and  inventories even fell
          considerably relative to sales. The decline in working capital affects investment directly since it
          implies a fall in internal funds, and indirectly by raising the cost of external funds.
          Bernanke and Gertler (1988) and Gertler (1989) argue that the agency cost of external finance
          depends on the quality of the balance sheet of the firm. When its liquidity decreases or when
          prospects concerning future sales deteriorate, the cost of external finance rises. Eckstein and
          Sinai (1986) found that at the end of the recession and at the beginning of a recovery firms try to
          rebuild their debt capacity by accumulating short-term financial assets in order to be able to
          borrow  at acceptable rates when they need  funds for  investment. According  to them  this
          re-liquefaction characterizes a separate phase of the business cycle that precedes the period in
          which firms start to invest again.
          A firm will also reduce inventories of materials during the recession as it will produce less.
          It is conceivable that firms also save working capital in order to make sure that it can carry out
          an investment plan that takes years without interruption due to lack of cash. Depending on the
          structure of the adjustment costs, working capital has still another effect on the investment
          process beyond those mentioned above. It will be used to smooth investments in the case of
          convex adjustment costs. If a fixed costs component dominates, investments decisions will seem
          irreversible.
          As Whited (1991) points out the height of the opportunity costs of reversing the investment
          decision varies with the cost of external finance which in turn depends on the availability of
          working capital inter alia. From the irreversibility literature we know that the higher the sunk
          costs, the longer a firm will wait to execute its investment plan ceteris paribus. Thus the size of
          the stock of working capital influences the timing (delay) of investment. Notice that working
          capital can be used for smoothing investment because it is in contrast to physical capital perfectly
          reversible. The amount of working capital that firms will hold for instance in order to make sure
          that investment plans don’t have to be interrupted depends among other things on their reputation
          in capital markets.
          For firms that are regarded as being of both high long term and high short term credit quality,
          Calomiris et al. (1994) find that they have lower stocks of inventories and financial working
          capital and in addition that these stocks are less sensitive to cash flow fluctuations. The latter
          finding is interpreted by them as follows. Firms of higher credit quality don’t need to accumulate
          working capital as a buffer against fluctuations in cash flow as they can easily obtain external
          funds at  favorable terms. Furthermore they show that given a high (long term) bond rating,
          only firms of large size, with low earnings variance, high cash flows and/or large stocks of





                                           LOVELY PROFESSIONAL UNIVERSITY                                   217
   217   218   219   220   221   222   223   224   225   226   227