Page 322 - DMGT308_CUSTOMER_RELATIONSHIP_MANAGEMENT
P. 322

Unit 12: Customer Privacy




          12.2.3 Wireless  Transmission                                                         Notes

          Market  forces  may also  be able  to  resolve  the unauthorized  eavesdropping  of  wireless
          communication  systems such as cellular and cordless telephones. True,  such monitoring is
          illegal for cellular calls (though not for cordless phones), but it is widely practiced by scanning
          hobbyists as well as investigators. Just ask Prince Charles.
          Eavesdropping is inefficient because it forces the participants in a communication to disguise
          the content of their transmissions, or to seek other ways of communicating.  Thus, there are
          incentives for cellular service providers or equipment firms to offer scrambling devices.

          Encryption systems require extra equipment and may increase the amount of spectrum required
          for a given quality and information content of a signal. Customers who value privacy sufficiently
          will be willing to pay for the increased resource cost.
          12.2.4 Data  Banks


          Companies often sell or pass along information about their customers to others, for a variety of
          purposes. Insurance companies want to know the accident and medical history of new applicants;
          stores, whether  new customers are credit-worthy; employers, whether  job applicants  have
          criminal histories; doctors, whether a patient has brought a malpractice suit in the past; and
          so on.
          In America individuals, firms, and governments have a substantial right to collect and redistribute
          personal and financial data about individuals. One could conceive of a market transaction system
          by which consumers offer companies payments to delete  such information or refrain from
          distributing it. But could such a  system work? In any transaction, both parties remain  with
          information about it. The problem is not usually that a party saves that information, but rather
          that it disseminates it to others. The regulatory approach restricts some of these transfers. Could
          a market work instead?
          The answer is usually “no” today and only “maybe,” in the future.
          The reason for this can be found in the logic of reselling information. In many cases the holder
          of information about a second party could share that information with a third party at a higher
          price that the resulting reduction in value to him. Take, for example, a piece of credit history
          information on individual A that is worth $5 to B so long as B retains the information exclusively.
          If B distributes the data to another party, C, the direct value of the data to B may not be diminished
          at all, or may drop a bit to, say, $4. (It is one of the peculiar economic properties of information
          that  it can usually be shared without  any or only little loss of usefulness to its holder.  The
          exceptions are business and trade secrets.) Suppose C, too, is willing to pay up to $4 for the same
          information because it is of similar usefulness to him. Then the total value to B of not destroying
          the information is $8. And why stop at two beneficiaries? B could resell the information also to
          D, E, etc. So could C. In each case, the reduction in value of the information to one of its holders
          may be less than what another party will gain by obtaining it.

          Hence the information will spread. Accordingly, the subject of the information, individual  A,
          might have to expend a significant amount of money to prevent B from spreading the information.
          If it is of use to a hundred firms, each valuing it at say $4, it would take a $396 “bribe” for  A to
          keep B from reselling it. If a resale of information is possible, B and C would market the same
          information about A, and they will drive down its price to the marginal costs of distribution. In
          that case, the information would spread greatly, but it would also be cheaper for A to bribe B at
          the outset. Yet all B would have to do is to contractually assure, in the transaction with C, against
          resale.






                                           LOVELY PROFESSIONAL UNIVERSITY                                   317
   317   318   319   320   321   322   323   324   325   326   327